1 00:00:00,040 --> 00:00:02,460 The following content is provided under a Creative 2 00:00:02,460 --> 00:00:03,870 Commons license. 3 00:00:03,870 --> 00:00:06,910 Your support will help MIT OpenCourseWare continue to 4 00:00:06,910 --> 00:00:10,560 offer high quality educational resources for free. 5 00:00:10,560 --> 00:00:13,460 To make a donation or view additional materials from 6 00:00:13,460 --> 00:00:18,815 hundreds of MIT courses, visit MIT OpenCourseWare at 7 00:00:18,815 --> 00:00:20,065 ocw.mit.edu. 8 00:00:23,990 --> 00:00:25,830 PROFESSOR: We want to turn this course to now start 9 00:00:25,830 --> 00:00:28,270 talking about some normative economics, which is how do we 10 00:00:28,270 --> 00:00:31,030 feel about the actions firms and consumers take. 11 00:00:31,030 --> 00:00:33,640 And to do that we need to pause, and starting last 12 00:00:33,640 --> 00:00:36,970 lecture now through this lecture, talk about welfare. 13 00:00:36,970 --> 00:00:37,980 Well-being. 14 00:00:37,980 --> 00:00:41,530 How do we measure the well-being implications of 15 00:00:41,530 --> 00:00:44,910 individual and firm actions? 16 00:00:44,910 --> 00:00:48,770 Now, we talked last time about the first concept of this, 17 00:00:48,770 --> 00:00:51,010 which was consumer surplus. 18 00:00:51,010 --> 00:00:57,840 Consumer surplus was the amount of utility consumers 19 00:00:57,840 --> 00:01:00,640 derived above and beyond the price they had 20 00:01:00,640 --> 00:01:01,670 to pay for the good. 21 00:01:01,670 --> 00:01:03,285 Now, since it's utility, remember, it's not ordinal, 22 00:01:03,285 --> 00:01:04,569 it's cardinal. 23 00:01:04,569 --> 00:01:06,130 We redefine that. 24 00:01:06,130 --> 00:01:09,680 That is the consumer's willingness to pay above the 25 00:01:09,680 --> 00:01:11,490 price that they pay for a good. 26 00:01:11,490 --> 00:01:14,380 So, anything a consumer's willing to pay that was higher 27 00:01:14,380 --> 00:01:18,730 than the price they actually paid is consumer surplus. 28 00:01:18,730 --> 00:01:20,050 And that was at the individual level. 29 00:01:20,050 --> 00:01:22,180 That was the individual consumer surplus. 30 00:01:22,180 --> 00:01:24,810 Now what we want to do is move on and talk about market 31 00:01:24,810 --> 00:01:26,060 consumer surplus. 32 00:01:29,250 --> 00:01:33,110 So for an individual, consumer surplus is a willingness to 33 00:01:33,110 --> 00:01:35,490 pay above the price actually paid. 34 00:01:35,490 --> 00:01:38,510 At the market level, it's the same thing. 35 00:01:38,510 --> 00:01:43,850 It's just the aggregation of individual consumer surpluses. 36 00:01:43,850 --> 00:01:46,870 So let's think about a simple example. 37 00:01:46,870 --> 00:01:50,630 Let's think about the case of the consumer surplus that you 38 00:01:50,630 --> 00:01:53,270 derive from my lectures. 39 00:01:53,270 --> 00:01:54,420 Let's think about the consumer surplus you 40 00:01:54,420 --> 00:01:56,120 derive from my lectures. 41 00:01:56,120 --> 00:01:58,180 So we have some demand curve for my lectures. 42 00:01:58,180 --> 00:02:00,410 Let's look at figure 13-1. 43 00:02:00,410 --> 00:02:03,910 Let's say this is the demand curve for my lectures. 44 00:02:03,910 --> 00:02:07,040 So basically, this is a willingness to pay. 45 00:02:07,040 --> 00:02:10,600 So the notion is that there's some student who's willing to 46 00:02:10,600 --> 00:02:12,740 pay a large amount because they recognize the brilliance 47 00:02:12,740 --> 00:02:14,020 of what they're hearing here. 48 00:02:14,020 --> 00:02:16,890 And they're willing to pay a large amount for my lectures. 49 00:02:16,890 --> 00:02:18,990 Then the next student's willing to pay slightly less. 50 00:02:18,990 --> 00:02:22,220 All the way down to the student who falls asleep every 51 00:02:22,220 --> 00:02:25,050 time who's not willing to pay anything for my lectures. 52 00:02:25,050 --> 00:02:26,770 So you've got some demand curve for my lectures. 53 00:02:26,770 --> 00:02:29,320 And, once again, the key to all this, the key to the 54 00:02:29,320 --> 00:02:31,820 welfare analysis, is to remember what this demand 55 00:02:31,820 --> 00:02:32,390 curve represents. 56 00:02:32,390 --> 00:02:34,370 It's a willingness to pay curve. 57 00:02:34,370 --> 00:02:36,260 But in this case, it's not an individual's 58 00:02:36,260 --> 00:02:36,962 willingness to pay. 59 00:02:36,962 --> 00:02:38,620 It's the market's willingness to pay. 60 00:02:38,620 --> 00:02:41,220 Where each point is a unit of demand. 61 00:02:41,220 --> 00:02:44,350 So in this case, one unit equals one person. 62 00:02:44,350 --> 00:02:45,900 So each point represents the willingness 63 00:02:45,900 --> 00:02:47,430 to pay of that person. 64 00:02:47,430 --> 00:02:49,995 So the point on the y-axis represents the willingness to 65 00:02:49,995 --> 00:02:53,450 pay of the person who most enjoys my lectures. 66 00:02:53,450 --> 00:02:55,320 Or derives the most value out of them. 67 00:02:55,320 --> 00:02:58,470 The intersection of that line with the x-axis is a 68 00:02:58,470 --> 00:02:59,910 willingness to pay of zero, someone who's not willing to 69 00:02:59,910 --> 00:03:02,130 pay anything for the lectures. 70 00:03:02,130 --> 00:03:03,150 Obviously, could go negative. 71 00:03:03,150 --> 00:03:05,600 People could be willing to pay not have to come to the 72 00:03:05,600 --> 00:03:07,170 lecture, but we won't consider that. 73 00:03:07,170 --> 00:03:10,000 We'll just say zero's the minimum. 74 00:03:10,000 --> 00:03:13,900 So, basically, what is the key determinant of 75 00:03:13,900 --> 00:03:15,950 the equilibrium outcome? 76 00:03:15,950 --> 00:03:20,270 It is the point where, equilibrium is the point, 77 00:03:20,270 --> 00:03:24,870 where the price is set equal to the willingness to pay of 78 00:03:24,870 --> 00:03:26,450 the marginal consumer. 79 00:03:26,450 --> 00:03:30,610 So if you think about typical supply-demand diagram, and we 80 00:03:30,610 --> 00:03:32,760 get some equilibrium price. 81 00:03:32,760 --> 00:03:35,260 So here's our equilibrium quantity, Q-star. 82 00:03:35,260 --> 00:03:37,690 And here's our program price, P-star. 83 00:03:37,690 --> 00:03:40,090 Now, let's focus in on this demand curve. 84 00:03:40,090 --> 00:03:43,690 With that price P-star, it represents-- 85 00:03:43,690 --> 00:03:46,770 it's on the demand curve, so it's a willingness to pay. 86 00:03:46,770 --> 00:03:48,670 Whose willingness to pay is it? 87 00:03:48,670 --> 00:03:51,450 It's the willingness to pay of person Q-star. 88 00:03:51,450 --> 00:03:54,420 It's the willingness to pay of the person who's exactly 89 00:03:54,420 --> 00:03:56,740 willing to pay the price. 90 00:03:56,740 --> 00:04:00,290 That is, the equilibrium in a perfectly competitive market, 91 00:04:00,290 --> 00:04:05,620 of the kind we've discussed so far, the price represents the 92 00:04:05,620 --> 00:04:08,900 willingness to pay of the marginal consumer. 93 00:04:08,900 --> 00:04:13,410 The willingness to pay of the consumer who exactly is 94 00:04:13,410 --> 00:04:16,640 indifferent between consuming and not consuming the good. 95 00:04:16,640 --> 00:04:20,839 So this consumer, Q-star, this person Q-star in our example, 96 00:04:20,839 --> 00:04:22,980 is the person who's indifferent. 97 00:04:22,980 --> 00:04:27,040 Who derives, what, zero consumer surplus. 98 00:04:27,040 --> 00:04:30,170 This person, since their willingness to pay equals the 99 00:04:30,170 --> 00:04:36,550 price, equilibrium is achieved where the price is set-- 100 00:04:36,550 --> 00:04:39,950 In equilibrium, you have that the marginal consumer, the 101 00:04:39,950 --> 00:04:42,240 last person consuming, is deriving 102 00:04:42,240 --> 00:04:44,190 zero consumer surplus. 103 00:04:44,190 --> 00:04:47,470 They're indifferent between consuming the good and not 104 00:04:47,470 --> 00:04:49,550 consuming the good at that price. 105 00:04:49,550 --> 00:04:51,780 If it was free, they'd be happy to consume it, but at 106 00:04:51,780 --> 00:04:54,090 the price, at that equilibrium price P-star, they're 107 00:04:54,090 --> 00:04:55,950 indifferent. 108 00:04:55,950 --> 00:04:59,270 So basically, looking at the diagram, what this is saying 109 00:04:59,270 --> 00:05:03,170 is that the price was $100 a lecture. 110 00:05:03,170 --> 00:05:07,530 Then person 100, that hundredth person, would be the 111 00:05:07,530 --> 00:05:11,460 marginal consumer who's indifferent between paying the 112 00:05:11,460 --> 00:05:13,710 $100 and hearing my lecture or paying nothing 113 00:05:13,710 --> 00:05:15,860 and skipping my lecture. 114 00:05:15,860 --> 00:05:19,180 So that person 100 is the person who's indifferent 115 00:05:19,180 --> 00:05:22,375 between paying $100 and hearing my lecture or paying 116 00:05:22,375 --> 00:05:23,880 zero and not hearing my lecture. 117 00:05:23,880 --> 00:05:27,670 That person drives no consumer surplus. 118 00:05:27,670 --> 00:05:30,290 Because their willingness to pay equals the price. 119 00:05:30,290 --> 00:05:34,550 What that means is that every consumer up to the first 100, 120 00:05:34,550 --> 00:05:36,740 by definition, must be deriving 121 00:05:36,740 --> 00:05:38,570 some consumer surplus. 122 00:05:38,570 --> 00:05:41,770 As long as the demand curve is downward sloping. 123 00:05:41,770 --> 00:05:44,270 As long as the demand curve is downward sloping, every person 124 00:05:44,270 --> 00:05:46,800 to the left of person 100 must be deriving 125 00:05:46,800 --> 00:05:48,690 some consumer surplus. 126 00:05:48,690 --> 00:05:51,340 In particular, the first person is driving enormous 127 00:05:51,340 --> 00:05:52,450 consumer surplus. 128 00:05:52,450 --> 00:05:53,200 How can we prove that? 129 00:05:53,200 --> 00:05:54,180 Well, the proof is simple. 130 00:05:54,180 --> 00:05:59,590 We know their willingness to pay is higher than person 100. 131 00:05:59,590 --> 00:06:02,810 And we know person 100 is willing to pay $100. 132 00:06:02,810 --> 00:06:05,470 Therefore, by definition anyone to the left is deriving 133 00:06:05,470 --> 00:06:07,860 consumer surplus from this. 134 00:06:07,860 --> 00:06:10,070 Because we know they like it more than person 100, and 135 00:06:10,070 --> 00:06:11,990 person 100 is willing to pay $100. 136 00:06:11,990 --> 00:06:15,000 They only have to pay $100, it's one price to everybody. 137 00:06:15,000 --> 00:06:18,540 So by definition, they're deriving consumer surplus. 138 00:06:18,540 --> 00:06:24,910 So the first guy, he or she gets a big consumer surplus. 139 00:06:24,910 --> 00:06:26,915 Then it dwindles and dwindles and dwindles until the 140 00:06:26,915 --> 00:06:28,670 hundredth person derives zero. 141 00:06:28,670 --> 00:06:32,250 But, if you integrate, and the entire consumer surplus for 142 00:06:32,250 --> 00:06:35,020 the market is that entire triangle, that 143 00:06:35,020 --> 00:06:36,570 entire shaded triangle. 144 00:06:36,570 --> 00:06:40,080 So market consumer surplus is defined the same as individual 145 00:06:40,080 --> 00:06:41,330 consumer surplus, as the difference 146 00:06:41,330 --> 00:06:42,420 between the demand curve. 147 00:06:42,420 --> 00:06:44,675 It's the area under the demand curve above the price. 148 00:06:44,675 --> 00:06:47,490 So it's the integral of that area, under the demand curve, 149 00:06:47,490 --> 00:06:49,250 above the price. 150 00:06:49,250 --> 00:06:51,220 But here we're thinking of it not in terms of a person's 151 00:06:51,220 --> 00:06:52,770 decision but the market's decision. 152 00:06:52,770 --> 00:06:54,870 And when you think about that, it is the last unit be 153 00:06:54,870 --> 00:06:56,730 representing the person who's indifferent. 154 00:06:56,730 --> 00:07:00,730 And everybody else deriving surplus from it. 155 00:07:00,730 --> 00:07:03,540 Questions about that? 156 00:07:03,540 --> 00:07:06,870 Now, let's ask what, then would happen if the price of 157 00:07:06,870 --> 00:07:08,750 my lecture rate rose. 158 00:07:08,750 --> 00:07:11,010 So let's say I was charging $100 boxes at the door. 159 00:07:11,010 --> 00:07:13,550 You guys are all the guys to the left of person 100. 160 00:07:13,550 --> 00:07:14,930 Those people who were here for the first lecture and don't 161 00:07:14,930 --> 00:07:16,620 show up any more, they're the people to the 162 00:07:16,620 --> 00:07:19,880 right of person 100. 163 00:07:19,880 --> 00:07:21,540 And now let's say I change. 164 00:07:21,540 --> 00:07:23,580 Instead of charging $100 at the door, I 165 00:07:23,580 --> 00:07:25,570 charge $110 at the door. 166 00:07:25,570 --> 00:07:29,350 So let's look at figure 13-2. 167 00:07:29,350 --> 00:07:31,630 What happens there? 168 00:07:31,630 --> 00:07:39,070 Well, in that case, if I charge $110, the hundredth guy 169 00:07:39,070 --> 00:07:41,190 is no longer willing to come to lecture. 170 00:07:41,190 --> 00:07:44,550 Remember, the hundredth guy, he or she was indifferent 171 00:07:44,550 --> 00:07:46,480 between paying $100 and hearing my lecture and paying 172 00:07:46,480 --> 00:07:47,840 nothing and missing my lecture. 173 00:07:47,840 --> 00:07:50,125 Well at $110, clearly, they'll say forget it, it's not worth 174 00:07:50,125 --> 00:07:50,900 it any more. 175 00:07:50,900 --> 00:07:52,450 They'll drop out. 176 00:07:52,450 --> 00:07:55,560 Likewise, the way I've drawn this diagram, everybody above 177 00:07:55,560 --> 00:07:58,960 person 90 will no longer attend. 178 00:07:58,960 --> 00:08:01,830 That is, person 90 is now the person, where at a price of 179 00:08:01,830 --> 00:08:04,820 $110 they're indifferent between paying and attending 180 00:08:04,820 --> 00:08:07,640 or not paying and not attending. 181 00:08:07,640 --> 00:08:09,830 Everybody to the left of person 90 still 182 00:08:09,830 --> 00:08:10,760 gets consumer surplus. 183 00:08:10,760 --> 00:08:12,990 It's not shaded, but if you shade the triangle above the 184 00:08:12,990 --> 00:08:16,230 $110 dashed line, the triangle under the demand curve and 185 00:08:16,230 --> 00:08:18,980 above with a dashed line at $110, that's the 186 00:08:18,980 --> 00:08:22,140 new consumer surplus. 187 00:08:22,140 --> 00:08:23,670 That's the new consumer surplus. 188 00:08:23,670 --> 00:08:25,280 Those people still derive consumer surplus because they 189 00:08:25,280 --> 00:08:29,250 love me so much that they're willing to pay more than $110. 190 00:08:29,250 --> 00:08:31,990 So even $110, and they prefer to pay $100. 191 00:08:31,990 --> 00:08:34,070 But even $110 they'll still come and they'll still be 192 00:08:34,070 --> 00:08:35,340 happy about it. 193 00:08:35,340 --> 00:08:37,940 But now 10 people have dropped out because they're not 194 00:08:37,940 --> 00:08:39,320 willing to pay $110. 195 00:08:39,320 --> 00:08:41,750 They were only willing to pay $100. 196 00:08:41,750 --> 00:08:44,540 So what we see is that the total 197 00:08:44,540 --> 00:08:46,450 consumer surplus has shrunk. 198 00:08:46,450 --> 00:08:51,910 It's shrunk by this trapezoid, by this shaded trapezoid. 199 00:08:51,910 --> 00:08:55,010 And it's shrunk for two reasons. 200 00:08:55,010 --> 00:08:59,180 One reason is that some people who used to derive consumer 201 00:08:59,180 --> 00:09:01,480 surplus now are out of the market. 202 00:09:01,480 --> 00:09:02,840 That's the triangle. 203 00:09:02,840 --> 00:09:05,240 That's the shaded triangle. 204 00:09:05,240 --> 00:09:08,730 It's also shrunk because even people staying in the market 205 00:09:08,730 --> 00:09:10,570 are now sadder. 206 00:09:10,570 --> 00:09:11,960 They've lost consumer surplus. 207 00:09:11,960 --> 00:09:14,010 The consumer surplus is still positive. 208 00:09:14,010 --> 00:09:16,400 They're still coming to the lecture, but it's smaller than 209 00:09:16,400 --> 00:09:18,860 it was, and that's the rectangle. 210 00:09:18,860 --> 00:09:22,530 So the triangle is the people who drop out of the market. 211 00:09:22,530 --> 00:09:27,210 The rectangle is the reduced consumer surplus, the reduced 212 00:09:27,210 --> 00:09:29,290 consumer surplus of people who stay in the market but now 213 00:09:29,290 --> 00:09:31,200 have to pay $10 more. 214 00:09:31,200 --> 00:09:33,100 The consumer surplus is still positive, but it's smaller. 215 00:09:35,960 --> 00:09:38,170 So, a question to you. 216 00:09:38,170 --> 00:09:44,170 What is the key economic concept that's going to 217 00:09:44,170 --> 00:09:48,360 determine, for a given market, whether the consumer surplus 218 00:09:48,360 --> 00:09:49,910 is large or small? 219 00:09:49,910 --> 00:09:50,760 Yeah? 220 00:09:50,760 --> 00:09:51,210 AUDIENCE: Elasticity. 221 00:09:51,210 --> 00:09:51,950 PROFESSOR: The elasticity. 222 00:09:51,950 --> 00:09:53,080 And why is that? 223 00:09:53,080 --> 00:09:56,890 AUDIENCE: Because it changes how steeply-- 224 00:09:56,890 --> 00:09:57,700 PROFESSOR: Exactly. 225 00:09:57,700 --> 00:10:04,820 So if we look at figure 13-3, now here is a case with a 226 00:10:04,820 --> 00:10:06,360 steeper elasticity of demand, where 227 00:10:06,360 --> 00:10:08,780 consumers are more inelastic. 228 00:10:08,780 --> 00:10:11,810 If you compare it to figure 13-1, you'll see the consumer 229 00:10:11,810 --> 00:10:15,660 surplus triangle is much bigger. 230 00:10:15,660 --> 00:10:20,030 Likewise, if we drew a flatter demand curve, a more elastic 231 00:10:20,030 --> 00:10:25,630 demand, the consumer surplus would be much smaller. 232 00:10:25,630 --> 00:10:27,450 So hopefully you can see graphically what will 233 00:10:27,450 --> 00:10:31,050 determine consumer surplus is the elasticity of demand. 234 00:10:31,050 --> 00:10:33,650 Now, can someone give me the intuition for why that's true? 235 00:10:33,650 --> 00:10:34,990 Graphically, I hope you can see it's true. 236 00:10:34,990 --> 00:10:38,030 The triangle will be smaller as that curve is flatter. 237 00:10:38,030 --> 00:10:40,010 Can someone give me the intuition for why that's true? 238 00:10:40,010 --> 00:10:42,890 Why is it that consumer surplus is larger the more 239 00:10:42,890 --> 00:10:45,575 inelastic is demand, and consumer surplus is smaller 240 00:10:45,575 --> 00:10:48,510 the more elastic is demand. 241 00:10:48,510 --> 00:10:50,294 Want to give it a try? 242 00:10:50,294 --> 00:10:52,754 AUDIENCE: I guess if it's more inelastic, then consumers 243 00:10:52,754 --> 00:10:56,200 don't have-- 244 00:10:56,200 --> 00:10:57,180 PROFESSOR: They don't have what? 245 00:10:57,180 --> 00:10:58,160 [UNINTELLIGIBLE] 246 00:10:58,160 --> 00:11:00,120 What determines it? 247 00:11:00,120 --> 00:11:00,420 AUDIENCE: As many choices, I would say. 248 00:11:00,420 --> 00:11:02,040 PROFESSOR: They don't have as many substitutes. 249 00:11:02,040 --> 00:11:05,500 So with inelastic demand is when consumers don't have as 250 00:11:05,500 --> 00:11:06,840 many substitutes. 251 00:11:06,840 --> 00:11:09,460 In that case they get a lot of surplus from 252 00:11:09,460 --> 00:11:10,850 consuming this good. 253 00:11:10,850 --> 00:11:14,310 So think about insulin versus McDonald's. 254 00:11:14,310 --> 00:11:17,980 The consumer surplus from insulin is very, very high. 255 00:11:17,980 --> 00:11:21,170 Because regardless of the price, I die without it. 256 00:11:21,170 --> 00:11:23,520 And there's no substitute. 257 00:11:23,520 --> 00:11:27,970 So it's a very inelastically demanded good, and as a 258 00:11:27,970 --> 00:11:31,670 result, at any price, I derive a huge consumer surplus 259 00:11:31,670 --> 00:11:33,730 because as long as that price is less than the value of my 260 00:11:33,730 --> 00:11:37,660 life, I derive a big consumer surplus. 261 00:11:37,660 --> 00:11:39,600 Now let's take McDonald's. 262 00:11:39,600 --> 00:11:42,780 I can always go to Burger King and be equally happy. 263 00:11:42,780 --> 00:11:44,280 Maybe not quite equally happy, the curve 264 00:11:44,280 --> 00:11:44,950 isn't perfectly elastic. 265 00:11:44,950 --> 00:11:46,160 I like McDonald's a little bit more. 266 00:11:46,160 --> 00:11:48,960 I like the prizes in their Happy Meals better. 267 00:11:48,960 --> 00:11:51,580 So it's a little bit elastic, but the point is, if 268 00:11:51,580 --> 00:11:55,320 McDonald's raises the price, I'm not that much sadder 269 00:11:55,320 --> 00:11:57,340 because I just go to Burger King where I was perfectly 270 00:11:57,340 --> 00:11:58,500 happy as well. 271 00:11:58,500 --> 00:12:00,830 So there's not much lost consumer surplus if McDonald's 272 00:12:00,830 --> 00:12:01,490 raises the price. 273 00:12:01,490 --> 00:12:05,710 There's not much consumer surplus arising. 274 00:12:05,710 --> 00:12:07,410 There's not that much consumer surplus-- 275 00:12:07,410 --> 00:12:08,120 forget the loss. 276 00:12:08,120 --> 00:12:08,990 Go back. 277 00:12:08,990 --> 00:12:10,270 That's a different issue. 278 00:12:10,270 --> 00:12:12,020 I'm talking the sides of the consumer surplus. 279 00:12:12,020 --> 00:12:14,480 There's not much consumer surplus arising from consuming 280 00:12:14,480 --> 00:12:16,890 at McDonald's. 281 00:12:16,890 --> 00:12:18,330 Not much consumer surplus arises from consuming 282 00:12:18,330 --> 00:12:19,200 McDonalds because I can always just go 283 00:12:19,200 --> 00:12:20,640 to Burger King instead. 284 00:12:20,640 --> 00:12:23,310 So what determines consumer surplus is the elasticity of 285 00:12:23,310 --> 00:12:29,060 demand, which is fundamentally about your willingness to pay. 286 00:12:29,060 --> 00:12:33,930 Inelastic goods have higher willingness to pay. 287 00:12:33,930 --> 00:12:37,660 And so as a result, the consumer surplus is 288 00:12:37,660 --> 00:12:41,030 essentially inversely related to the elasticity of demand. 289 00:12:41,030 --> 00:12:43,535 The higher the elasticity, the smaller the consumer surplus. 290 00:12:48,970 --> 00:12:52,230 Now, let's shift and talk about producers. 291 00:12:52,230 --> 00:12:56,810 The analysis for producer surplus is exactly the same 292 00:12:56,810 --> 00:12:58,320 type of analysis, just flipped to the 293 00:12:58,320 --> 00:13:01,320 other side of the market. 294 00:13:01,320 --> 00:13:07,160 Now, here the question is, what 295 00:13:07,160 --> 00:13:08,650 determines my producer surplus? 296 00:13:08,650 --> 00:13:10,720 Well, what determines consumer surplus? 297 00:13:10,720 --> 00:13:13,330 It's the difference between my marginal willingness to pay 298 00:13:13,330 --> 00:13:14,820 and the price. 299 00:13:14,820 --> 00:13:17,540 What determines producer surplus, that's going to be 300 00:13:17,540 --> 00:13:20,880 the difference between the firm's marginal willingness to 301 00:13:20,880 --> 00:13:24,160 supply, and the price. 302 00:13:24,160 --> 00:13:28,140 So my marginal willingness to pay as a consumer is what 303 00:13:28,140 --> 00:13:30,190 determines my consumer surplus. 304 00:13:30,190 --> 00:13:32,890 Producer surplus will be determined by my marginal 305 00:13:32,890 --> 00:13:34,140 willingness to supply. 306 00:13:36,630 --> 00:13:39,730 My marginal is supply, which is simply represented by the 307 00:13:39,730 --> 00:13:41,820 supply curve. 308 00:13:41,820 --> 00:13:43,380 A little bit easier for producer surplus. 309 00:13:43,380 --> 00:13:46,970 The supply curve represents the price at which I'm willing 310 00:13:46,970 --> 00:13:48,350 to supply a good. 311 00:13:48,350 --> 00:13:49,820 That's what a supply curve is. 312 00:13:49,820 --> 00:13:53,440 As we learned a couple lectures ago, in the context 313 00:13:53,440 --> 00:13:57,580 of competitive firms that's my marginal cost. So the supply 314 00:13:57,580 --> 00:14:02,950 curve is my marginal cost. That says that is how much it 315 00:14:02,950 --> 00:14:05,490 costs me to produce the next unit. 316 00:14:05,490 --> 00:14:08,255 In a perfectly competitive long-run equilibrium, or short 317 00:14:08,255 --> 00:14:13,870 run equilibrium, that is basically what I'll 318 00:14:13,870 --> 00:14:17,240 set my price to. 319 00:14:17,240 --> 00:14:23,900 So if we go to figure 13-4, now let's look 320 00:14:23,900 --> 00:14:26,090 at my producer surplus. 321 00:14:26,090 --> 00:14:28,510 My surplus from delivering lectures. 322 00:14:28,510 --> 00:14:30,140 Let's say that-- 323 00:14:30,140 --> 00:14:31,290 this is a bit harder to imagine-- 324 00:14:31,290 --> 00:14:35,250 but imagine that I prefer deliver smaller lectures. 325 00:14:35,250 --> 00:14:38,310 Maybe because as the number of kids gets smaller I can learn 326 00:14:38,310 --> 00:14:38,745 your names. 327 00:14:38,745 --> 00:14:40,760 I don't have to look around as much, I don't have to pace as 328 00:14:40,760 --> 00:14:42,690 much, whatever. 329 00:14:42,690 --> 00:14:44,950 So imagine that I'm most happy delivering a 330 00:14:44,950 --> 00:14:47,010 lecture to one student. 331 00:14:47,010 --> 00:14:50,080 And that's the lowest cost to me, the lowest effort. 332 00:14:50,080 --> 00:14:52,320 I can just come in and sit down, and we have coffee and I 333 00:14:52,320 --> 00:14:54,020 just riff, and I don't have to worry about notes or any of 334 00:14:54,020 --> 00:14:55,080 that stuff. 335 00:14:55,080 --> 00:14:57,160 But when there's two students I feel a little bit guilty 336 00:14:57,160 --> 00:14:59,200 doing that, so I make some notes to myself. 337 00:14:59,200 --> 00:15:01,030 When there's three students I make some more notes. 338 00:15:01,030 --> 00:15:03,070 By the time there's all you students, I have to type up 339 00:15:03,070 --> 00:15:04,780 all these notes. 340 00:15:04,780 --> 00:15:08,520 So every student that adds to my lecture, imagine, is a 341 00:15:08,520 --> 00:15:09,130 marginal cost. 342 00:15:09,130 --> 00:15:10,200 Now, you know that's not true, of course. 343 00:15:10,200 --> 00:15:12,680 I wouldn't change my notes if six more students walked in. 344 00:15:12,680 --> 00:15:15,950 But let's just imagine that it's linear. 345 00:15:15,950 --> 00:15:19,000 Imagine with every student that comes in here, I have to 346 00:15:19,000 --> 00:15:21,580 put in a little more effort in my lecture. 347 00:15:21,580 --> 00:15:25,200 So it's a marginal cost to me with the additional students. 348 00:15:25,200 --> 00:15:27,680 So that delivers the supply curve, this upward sloping 349 00:15:27,680 --> 00:15:30,450 supply curve. 350 00:15:30,450 --> 00:15:34,040 Now let's say at a given price, P, I'm willing to 351 00:15:34,040 --> 00:15:37,100 lecture-- so that, given the supply curve, if the price is 352 00:15:37,100 --> 00:15:41,910 equal to p, I'm willing to lecture to Q students. 353 00:15:41,910 --> 00:15:45,940 That is, if you're going to give me a price of P, at that 354 00:15:45,940 --> 00:15:51,010 price my marginal willingness to supply is that I'll supply 355 00:15:51,010 --> 00:15:52,260 Q lectures. 356 00:15:54,800 --> 00:15:57,260 So another way to say it is that if you want me to supply 357 00:15:57,260 --> 00:16:00,880 Q lectures, you've got to pay me a price P. That's the point 358 00:16:00,880 --> 00:16:03,950 where I derive no producer surplus. 359 00:16:03,950 --> 00:16:06,080 I'm indifferent at that point. 360 00:16:06,080 --> 00:16:11,010 If at that point you said, would you want the Q-th 361 00:16:11,010 --> 00:16:12,910 student or not, I'd say I don't really care. 362 00:16:12,910 --> 00:16:14,750 I'm indifferent. 363 00:16:14,750 --> 00:16:16,300 I get zero producer surplus. 364 00:16:16,300 --> 00:16:18,770 But, I got a huge surplus on that first student. 365 00:16:18,770 --> 00:16:20,650 Because I was willing to work with them and it wouldn't have 366 00:16:20,650 --> 00:16:21,790 cost me anything. 367 00:16:21,790 --> 00:16:24,560 But I'm getting paid P to work with all of you. 368 00:16:24,560 --> 00:16:26,710 So I make a producer surplus on that. 369 00:16:26,710 --> 00:16:31,470 So producer surplus is made on every unit to the left of Q, 370 00:16:31,470 --> 00:16:36,250 because those are units with a positive producer surplus. 371 00:16:36,250 --> 00:16:39,810 They're the units above the supply curve 372 00:16:39,810 --> 00:16:42,200 and below the price. 373 00:16:42,200 --> 00:16:44,610 They're the units where it's above the supply curve, so I'm 374 00:16:44,610 --> 00:16:47,430 willing to supply, but below the price which means that I'm 375 00:16:47,430 --> 00:16:51,320 getting paid more than I would have to to supply that unit. 376 00:16:51,320 --> 00:16:52,850 Can anyone think of another name for 377 00:16:52,850 --> 00:16:54,130 this triangle, roughly? 378 00:16:54,130 --> 00:16:55,535 How else you might think about that triangle. 379 00:16:58,400 --> 00:16:59,770 Well, I can talk about producer surplus. 380 00:16:59,770 --> 00:17:02,340 And I said, what's the difference between the price 381 00:17:02,340 --> 00:17:05,819 producers receive and the cost that they have to produce it. 382 00:17:05,819 --> 00:17:06,359 AUDIENCE: Profit. 383 00:17:06,359 --> 00:17:07,720 PROFESSOR: Profit. 384 00:17:07,720 --> 00:17:10,750 Roughly speaking, producer surplus is profit. 385 00:17:10,750 --> 00:17:13,910 Now, technically, in the short run, that's not true. 386 00:17:13,910 --> 00:17:15,770 Because in the short run there's fixed costs and you 387 00:17:15,770 --> 00:17:17,740 might lose money on fixed costs and still make a long 388 00:17:17,740 --> 00:17:18,359 run profit. 389 00:17:18,359 --> 00:17:20,599 So in the short run it's not technically true. 390 00:17:20,599 --> 00:17:22,410 In the long run it is technically true, and for the 391 00:17:22,410 --> 00:17:24,780 purpose of this course we'll say it's technically true. 392 00:17:24,780 --> 00:17:26,440 So producer surplus is profit. 393 00:17:26,440 --> 00:17:28,010 It's a lot easier to think about. 394 00:17:28,010 --> 00:17:30,850 Consumer surplus is this vague concept we have to measure my 395 00:17:30,850 --> 00:17:33,300 willingness to pay versus what I pay. 396 00:17:33,300 --> 00:17:36,590 Producer surplus is easy, it's profit. 397 00:17:36,590 --> 00:17:41,070 So producer surplus is profit, it's the difference between 398 00:17:41,070 --> 00:17:43,160 the price at which I'm willing to produce the good and the 399 00:17:43,160 --> 00:17:46,150 price you actually pay me for it. 400 00:17:46,150 --> 00:17:48,400 So that's producer surplus. 401 00:17:48,400 --> 00:17:51,230 Questions about that? 402 00:17:51,230 --> 00:17:52,110 OK. 403 00:17:52,110 --> 00:17:55,950 Putting this together, we can now measure the total welfare 404 00:17:55,950 --> 00:17:56,970 of society. 405 00:17:56,970 --> 00:17:57,763 We now have it. 406 00:17:57,763 --> 00:18:00,650 We can measure the entire happiness of all of society. 407 00:18:00,650 --> 00:18:07,300 And we define social welfare of society as consumer surplus 408 00:18:07,300 --> 00:18:10,520 plus producer surplus. 409 00:18:10,520 --> 00:18:13,100 Now, that doesn't have to be. 410 00:18:13,100 --> 00:18:16,130 You could say, gee, Jon, don't you care more about consumers 411 00:18:16,130 --> 00:18:17,230 than firms? 412 00:18:17,230 --> 00:18:18,730 Or gee, Jon, don't you care more 413 00:18:18,730 --> 00:18:19,260 about firms than consumers. 414 00:18:19,260 --> 00:18:20,770 I'm going to leave that alone for now. 415 00:18:20,770 --> 00:18:23,380 We're just going to do the simplest thing and just say, 416 00:18:23,380 --> 00:18:27,670 we're going to define social welfare as simply the sum of 417 00:18:27,670 --> 00:18:30,300 how much surplus consumers get plus how much surplus 418 00:18:30,300 --> 00:18:32,730 producers get. 419 00:18:32,730 --> 00:18:33,420 OK? 420 00:18:33,420 --> 00:18:34,610 This is a particular representation. 421 00:18:34,610 --> 00:18:36,835 When we talk about efficiency and equilibrium, we're talking 422 00:18:36,835 --> 00:18:37,560 about efficiency-- 423 00:18:37,560 --> 00:18:38,400 I'm sorry-- 424 00:18:38,400 --> 00:18:41,260 versus equity, which we'll talk about towards the end of 425 00:18:41,260 --> 00:18:41,870 the course. 426 00:18:41,870 --> 00:18:45,080 We'll talk about alternative definitions, and how we weigh 427 00:18:45,080 --> 00:18:46,390 different definitions of this. 428 00:18:46,390 --> 00:18:48,760 But for now, this is the standard economic definition. 429 00:18:48,760 --> 00:18:50,460 Which is, let's not draw a judgment about 430 00:18:50,460 --> 00:18:51,910 who's better than who. 431 00:18:51,910 --> 00:18:53,230 Let's just talk about the total amount 432 00:18:53,230 --> 00:18:55,670 of surplus in society. 433 00:18:55,670 --> 00:18:58,940 So the amount of social welfare, is the total amount 434 00:18:58,940 --> 00:19:00,320 of surplus in society. 435 00:19:00,320 --> 00:19:03,440 And here's the key result. 436 00:19:03,440 --> 00:19:08,880 That the competitive equilibrium, where demand 437 00:19:08,880 --> 00:19:13,010 equals supply, in competitive equilibrium, is the welfare 438 00:19:13,010 --> 00:19:15,890 maximizing outcome. 439 00:19:15,890 --> 00:19:18,910 The competitive equilibrium of the market, which is where 440 00:19:18,910 --> 00:19:21,620 demand equals supply, is also the 441 00:19:21,620 --> 00:19:23,350 welfare maximizing outcome. 442 00:19:26,310 --> 00:19:29,220 And that's the key thing we want to go to now, which is 443 00:19:29,220 --> 00:19:32,700 that basically moving away from that equilibrium point, 444 00:19:32,700 --> 00:19:36,310 where demand equals supply, will by definition lower the 445 00:19:36,310 --> 00:19:38,490 amount of social welfare. 446 00:19:38,490 --> 00:19:45,430 So to see this, let's go to Figure 13-5. 447 00:19:45,430 --> 00:19:47,313 And we've got some supply and demand curves. 448 00:19:47,313 --> 00:19:48,280 This is from the book now. 449 00:19:48,280 --> 00:19:50,880 We've got some supply and demand curves. 450 00:19:50,880 --> 00:19:55,880 And we're initially in equilibrium at P1 Q1, 451 00:19:55,880 --> 00:19:57,520 at the point E1. 452 00:19:57,520 --> 00:20:01,350 So we're initially at equilibrium at E1. 453 00:20:01,350 --> 00:20:06,840 At E1, at that initial equilibrium point, consumer 454 00:20:06,840 --> 00:20:12,190 surplus is equal to R. Now, going by the letters that 455 00:20:12,190 --> 00:20:17,680 label the areas, R plus S plus V. That's the amount of 456 00:20:17,680 --> 00:20:18,020 consumer surplus. 457 00:20:18,020 --> 00:20:20,590 The amount under the demand curve, above the price. 458 00:20:23,110 --> 00:20:24,120 That's consumer surplus. 459 00:20:24,120 --> 00:20:27,120 Stop me if this is not clear, this is important stuff. 460 00:20:27,120 --> 00:20:29,560 So under the demand curve above the price, R plus S plus 461 00:20:29,560 --> 00:20:36,880 V. The producer surplus is T plus U. The profit is the 462 00:20:36,880 --> 00:20:40,800 amount above the supply curve and below the price. 463 00:20:40,800 --> 00:20:44,930 And so total social welfare is the sum of all these. 464 00:20:44,930 --> 00:20:50,170 R plus S plus V plus T plus U. That's our starting point. 465 00:20:50,170 --> 00:20:54,370 That's our competitive equilibrium starting point. 466 00:20:54,370 --> 00:20:56,400 Now, let's see. 467 00:20:56,400 --> 00:20:58,530 You should be able to immediately see, those of you 468 00:20:58,530 --> 00:21:01,160 who are good with your geometry, that there is no 469 00:21:01,160 --> 00:21:04,100 point you could choose which can make 470 00:21:04,100 --> 00:21:05,930 social welfare larger. 471 00:21:05,930 --> 00:21:08,840 As a simple comparative statics exercise, imagine I 472 00:21:08,840 --> 00:21:10,950 had the government come in and say, we're going to raise the 473 00:21:10,950 --> 00:21:13,210 prices in the market to P2. 474 00:21:13,210 --> 00:21:15,260 We decide that producers aren't making enough. 475 00:21:15,260 --> 00:21:17,770 Look, the consumers get three letters, the producers only 476 00:21:17,770 --> 00:21:20,460 get two letters, that's unfair. 477 00:21:20,460 --> 00:21:22,040 So we're going to raise the price to give the produces 478 00:21:22,040 --> 00:21:23,700 more letters and the consumer fewer letters. 479 00:21:23,700 --> 00:21:25,500 That sounds like about the rational basis for government 480 00:21:25,500 --> 00:21:27,770 policy making these days. 481 00:21:27,770 --> 00:21:29,870 So we're going to do that. 482 00:21:29,870 --> 00:21:32,460 And so we're going to raise the price to P2. 483 00:21:32,460 --> 00:21:37,160 With a price of P2, we'll have a new equilibrium. 484 00:21:37,160 --> 00:21:39,990 If you force the price up to P2. 485 00:21:39,990 --> 00:21:44,120 You have a new equilibrium at little e sub 2, and 486 00:21:44,120 --> 00:21:45,830 a quantity of Q2. 487 00:21:45,830 --> 00:21:46,680 What happens now? 488 00:21:46,680 --> 00:21:48,660 What's happened to consumer surplus? 489 00:21:48,660 --> 00:21:55,415 Consumer surplus, you've now lost S and V. Consumer surplus 490 00:21:55,415 --> 00:21:58,820 is now just R. Because at that new price, P2, that's the area 491 00:21:58,820 --> 00:22:01,620 under the demand curve above the price. 492 00:22:01,620 --> 00:22:03,150 Producer surplus has grown, however. 493 00:22:03,150 --> 00:22:10,580 Now, instead of being T plus U, it's now T plus S. So 494 00:22:10,580 --> 00:22:15,070 what's happened, effectively, is you've transferred S from 495 00:22:15,070 --> 00:22:18,650 consumers to producers. 496 00:22:18,650 --> 00:22:21,890 And you've lost V plus U, forever. 497 00:22:24,850 --> 00:22:26,790 So what's involved in this change is a 498 00:22:26,790 --> 00:22:28,800 transfer and a loss. 499 00:22:28,800 --> 00:22:31,710 The transfer is the area S, which used to belong to 500 00:22:31,710 --> 00:22:34,240 consumers now belongs to producers. 501 00:22:34,240 --> 00:22:39,770 But now we have what we call a dead weight loss. 502 00:22:39,770 --> 00:22:48,340 Dead weight loss, of V plus U. That's welfare that has 503 00:22:48,340 --> 00:22:49,590 disappeared. 504 00:22:51,470 --> 00:22:53,350 Welfare has disappeared. 505 00:22:53,350 --> 00:22:56,900 And the definition of dead weight loss is a net reduction 506 00:22:56,900 --> 00:23:01,190 in efficiency from trades that are not made. 507 00:23:01,190 --> 00:23:02,640 Remember we talked about efficiency 508 00:23:02,640 --> 00:23:04,040 early on in the course. 509 00:23:04,040 --> 00:23:08,470 We said the efficient outcome is one where trades that make 510 00:23:08,470 --> 00:23:11,810 both people better off are made. 511 00:23:11,810 --> 00:23:14,800 Here we have trades, which absent the government would 512 00:23:14,800 --> 00:23:17,790 have made both parties better off, 513 00:23:17,790 --> 00:23:19,960 and they're not happening. 514 00:23:19,960 --> 00:23:22,010 That is surplus that's just gone. 515 00:23:22,010 --> 00:23:24,660 It's into the ether. 516 00:23:24,660 --> 00:23:28,110 That is social surplus that is now social welfare, that is 517 00:23:28,110 --> 00:23:30,240 now gone because there are trades that would have made 518 00:23:30,240 --> 00:23:35,390 both parties happier that are now not happening. 519 00:23:35,390 --> 00:23:39,460 And that's a total waste from society's perspective. 520 00:23:39,460 --> 00:23:42,390 Because society's best off if all the trades that make both 521 00:23:42,390 --> 00:23:45,430 parties happier, happen. 522 00:23:45,430 --> 00:23:50,640 So the bottom line is, any price you would impose other 523 00:23:50,640 --> 00:23:54,060 than the market price of P1, and you can work this out for 524 00:23:54,060 --> 00:24:01,210 yourself, any price you would impose would by definition 525 00:24:01,210 --> 00:24:04,110 lead to a lower social welfare. 526 00:24:04,110 --> 00:24:05,090 It may shift. 527 00:24:05,090 --> 00:24:07,010 It may lead to a bigger or smaller consumer surplus 528 00:24:07,010 --> 00:24:08,860 relative to producer surplus. 529 00:24:08,860 --> 00:24:11,230 Once again at this point we're just using the sum of them as 530 00:24:11,230 --> 00:24:12,830 a measure of social welfare. 531 00:24:12,830 --> 00:24:15,940 Social welfare has fallen. 532 00:24:15,940 --> 00:24:19,250 So social welfare is maximized in this case. 533 00:24:19,250 --> 00:24:23,240 So this gives us a framework to think about. 534 00:24:23,240 --> 00:24:26,620 We started the course with supply and demand, and talking 535 00:24:26,620 --> 00:24:29,690 about how things like the minimum wage reduce 536 00:24:29,690 --> 00:24:30,910 efficiency. 537 00:24:30,910 --> 00:24:33,190 Well, this gives us a welfare framework, a more formal 538 00:24:33,190 --> 00:24:35,690 welfare framework, for thinking about that. 539 00:24:35,690 --> 00:24:38,260 I said it reduces efficiency before because you had less 540 00:24:38,260 --> 00:24:39,450 labor in the market. 541 00:24:39,450 --> 00:24:41,740 But now we can actually more formally say why does the 542 00:24:41,740 --> 00:24:44,040 minimum wage reduce efficiency? 543 00:24:44,040 --> 00:24:45,040 We can actually look at that. 544 00:24:45,040 --> 00:24:47,500 Let me just do the always-risky thing of trying a 545 00:24:47,500 --> 00:24:49,790 freehand diagram. 546 00:24:49,790 --> 00:24:52,380 You remember our market for labor, you had the amount of 547 00:24:52,380 --> 00:24:58,160 labor on the x-axis, the wage on the y-axis. 548 00:24:58,160 --> 00:25:02,470 You had some supply of labor that comes from workers 549 00:25:02,470 --> 00:25:05,340 deciding to work as the wage goes up, they 550 00:25:05,340 --> 00:25:06,510 want to work more. 551 00:25:06,510 --> 00:25:08,440 You've got demand for labor. 552 00:25:08,440 --> 00:25:11,230 That comes from firms demanding workers. 553 00:25:11,230 --> 00:25:14,430 As the wage goes up, they want fewer workers. 554 00:25:14,430 --> 00:25:19,790 And you have some initial equilibrium, L-star, W-star. 555 00:25:19,790 --> 00:25:22,560 When the government came in with its minimum wage and the 556 00:25:22,560 --> 00:25:25,060 government said, we're going to impose a minimum wage of 557 00:25:25,060 --> 00:25:28,890 W-bar, W-super bar. 558 00:25:28,890 --> 00:25:31,200 OK Remember, we said what happened was, well, of course 559 00:25:31,200 --> 00:25:34,965 then firms are only going to want L1 workers. 560 00:25:38,250 --> 00:25:41,720 We talked before about how that led to some unemployment. 561 00:25:41,720 --> 00:25:43,850 What we didn't mention is how this leads to an efficiency 562 00:25:43,850 --> 00:25:45,910 loss to society. 563 00:25:45,910 --> 00:25:49,540 This area is now dead weight loss. 564 00:25:49,540 --> 00:25:55,020 These workers, who would have been happy to work at the 565 00:25:55,020 --> 00:25:58,210 prevailing wage, and firms would have been happy to hire 566 00:25:58,210 --> 00:26:00,830 the workers at the prevailing wage, and those trades no 567 00:26:00,830 --> 00:26:03,900 longer happen. 568 00:26:03,900 --> 00:26:06,750 So here's an important question to help you think-- 569 00:26:06,750 --> 00:26:08,580 you're going to have to draw dead weight loss triangles in 570 00:26:08,580 --> 00:26:09,310 your sleep now. 571 00:26:09,310 --> 00:26:12,970 So here's the trick with these. 572 00:26:12,970 --> 00:26:16,230 Why is the dead weight loss triangle smallest here and 573 00:26:16,230 --> 00:26:17,800 grow like that? 574 00:26:17,800 --> 00:26:21,690 Why does the dead weight loss triangle grow as you move away 575 00:26:21,690 --> 00:26:22,790 from the competitive equilibrium? 576 00:26:22,790 --> 00:26:23,143 Yeah. 577 00:26:23,143 --> 00:26:26,028 AUDIENCE: There is less amount of people who are willing to 578 00:26:26,028 --> 00:26:28,850 work at that price. 579 00:26:28,850 --> 00:26:30,129 PROFESSOR: Say it again? 580 00:26:30,129 --> 00:26:33,242 AUDIENCE: So there's less people that are willing to 581 00:26:33,242 --> 00:26:35,480 work for that smaller price. 582 00:26:35,480 --> 00:26:37,723 PROFESSOR: Well, here we're imposing a higher-- less 583 00:26:37,723 --> 00:26:39,250 people are willing to work for, are you 584 00:26:39,250 --> 00:26:40,320 referring to here or here? 585 00:26:40,320 --> 00:26:41,760 AUDIENCE: To all the way to the right. 586 00:26:41,760 --> 00:26:42,420 PROFESSOR: All the way. 587 00:26:42,420 --> 00:26:45,140 So basically, the point is-- another way to put it is, at 588 00:26:45,140 --> 00:26:49,330 that wage the consumers there are pretty indifferent. 589 00:26:49,330 --> 00:26:53,770 So in other words, they're willing to work but barely. 590 00:26:53,770 --> 00:26:59,420 So at this wage, at this point here, the L*-th worker is 591 00:26:59,420 --> 00:27:01,660 getting no surplus from working. 592 00:27:01,660 --> 00:27:03,640 It's not a crappy wage, he's happy to take it. 593 00:27:03,640 --> 00:27:05,290 But he'd also be happy to sit at home. 594 00:27:05,290 --> 00:27:06,600 He's indifferent. 595 00:27:06,600 --> 00:27:09,960 So for that L*-th worker, you make him not 596 00:27:09,960 --> 00:27:12,040 work, he doesn't care. 597 00:27:12,040 --> 00:27:14,660 So if you raise the minimum wage and this guy sits at home 598 00:27:14,660 --> 00:27:16,380 instead of working, he didn't care. 599 00:27:16,380 --> 00:27:18,610 He was getting no surplus from working anyway. 600 00:27:18,610 --> 00:27:21,560 Likewise this firm, who's hiring the L*-th worker, they 601 00:27:21,560 --> 00:27:25,110 were paying this worker exactly what he was producing. 602 00:27:25,110 --> 00:27:28,990 The marginal cost of that worker exactly equalled what 603 00:27:28,990 --> 00:27:30,200 they were paying him. 604 00:27:30,200 --> 00:27:31,662 What that worker's producing was exactly equal to 605 00:27:31,662 --> 00:27:32,170 what they paid him. 606 00:27:32,170 --> 00:27:34,260 They were earning zero profit on that worker. 607 00:27:34,260 --> 00:27:36,340 So they don't care if he stays home. 608 00:27:36,340 --> 00:27:39,480 So if the government set a minimum wage, such that one 609 00:27:39,480 --> 00:27:43,600 guy stayed home, the minimum wage was so close to market 610 00:27:43,600 --> 00:27:47,000 wage that one guy stayed home, there would be no social 611 00:27:47,000 --> 00:27:48,380 welfare loss. 612 00:27:48,380 --> 00:27:50,260 Or infinitesimally small. 613 00:27:50,260 --> 00:27:52,870 Because that last guy, there was indifference on both the 614 00:27:52,870 --> 00:27:55,640 worker's side and the firm's side. 615 00:27:55,640 --> 00:27:58,160 However once you start displacing more and more, 616 00:27:58,160 --> 00:27:59,910 these workers aren't indifferent anymore, right? 617 00:27:59,910 --> 00:28:01,470 These are workers who were making a lot of 618 00:28:01,470 --> 00:28:02,930 surplus at that wage. 619 00:28:02,930 --> 00:28:05,180 And firms that were earning a lot of profit at that wage. 620 00:28:05,180 --> 00:28:06,800 Now they're not indifferent. 621 00:28:06,800 --> 00:28:09,030 So as you move farther and farther from the competitive 622 00:28:09,030 --> 00:28:12,420 equilibrium, the distortion gets larger and larger. 623 00:28:12,420 --> 00:28:16,780 Very important intuition to have. That for that last 624 00:28:16,780 --> 00:28:22,150 person, there's no distortion from moving epsilon away from 625 00:28:22,150 --> 00:28:23,370 the competitive equilibrium. 626 00:28:23,370 --> 00:28:25,240 Because they weren't earning any surplus anyway. 627 00:28:25,240 --> 00:28:27,450 And the firm wasn't making any surplus on them. 628 00:28:27,450 --> 00:28:31,880 But as you move away, the loss in social welfare gets larger 629 00:28:31,880 --> 00:28:35,180 and larger because these are people who are making all 630 00:28:35,180 --> 00:28:37,070 sorts of surpluses on these transactions. 631 00:28:37,070 --> 00:28:38,740 And you're stopping them from happening. 632 00:28:38,740 --> 00:28:40,630 So if the government interferes with the 633 00:28:40,630 --> 00:28:42,530 transaction-- 634 00:28:42,530 --> 00:28:44,710 So imagine, this guy and I were negotiating over a 635 00:28:44,710 --> 00:28:49,020 baseball card and I ended up paying him exactly what the 636 00:28:49,020 --> 00:28:50,530 baseball card was worth to him. 637 00:28:50,530 --> 00:28:51,930 And I ended up paying exactly what it was worth 638 00:28:51,930 --> 00:28:53,690 to me to have it. 639 00:28:53,690 --> 00:28:56,950 And then my parents come in and say, you can't do that. 640 00:28:56,950 --> 00:28:59,180 Then it doesn't really matter, because we weren't making any 641 00:28:59,180 --> 00:29:01,180 surplus of that trade anyway. 642 00:29:01,180 --> 00:29:05,330 But, if he had three of these cards and was delighted to get 643 00:29:05,330 --> 00:29:08,293 rid of it for $50, and I have always wanted this card and 644 00:29:08,293 --> 00:29:11,730 valued it at $200, then if my parents come and sink this 645 00:29:11,730 --> 00:29:14,040 trade, then that's a real bummer. 646 00:29:14,040 --> 00:29:16,410 That's a huge loss in social welfare, because the trade 647 00:29:16,410 --> 00:29:20,060 that made both parties better off is not happening. 648 00:29:20,060 --> 00:29:23,050 Questions about that? 649 00:29:23,050 --> 00:29:26,510 Let's look at a particularly good example of this. 650 00:29:26,510 --> 00:29:29,060 Of when the government interferes with trades and the 651 00:29:29,060 --> 00:29:29,480 implications of that. 652 00:29:29,480 --> 00:29:31,340 The TAs on Friday are going to go through a bunch of 653 00:29:31,340 --> 00:29:32,530 interesting examples. 654 00:29:32,530 --> 00:29:34,000 I'm just going to do one today. 655 00:29:34,000 --> 00:29:35,560 And then you'll do some more in section, because this is 656 00:29:35,560 --> 00:29:36,930 hard and important. 657 00:29:36,930 --> 00:29:40,370 I want to today focus on the example of taxicab medallions. 658 00:29:40,370 --> 00:29:41,620 It's the example in the book, which is a 659 00:29:41,620 --> 00:29:43,850 particularly good example. 660 00:29:43,850 --> 00:29:47,850 Taxi drivers, we've all taken taxis, we know how they work. 661 00:29:47,850 --> 00:29:52,210 But taxi drivers in virtually all cities, you cannot just 662 00:29:52,210 --> 00:29:54,710 start a cab and drive people around. 663 00:29:54,710 --> 00:29:57,950 In virtually all cities, you need to get something from the 664 00:29:57,950 --> 00:30:01,660 city that allows you to call yourself a taxicab. 665 00:30:01,660 --> 00:30:04,080 And that's typically called a taxicab medallion. 666 00:30:04,080 --> 00:30:06,470 It originally was literally something you had on the hood 667 00:30:06,470 --> 00:30:07,360 of your car. 668 00:30:07,360 --> 00:30:10,150 Now it's a certificate you have in the back of your car. 669 00:30:10,150 --> 00:30:12,100 So you see the certificate whenever you ride in a car, 670 00:30:12,100 --> 00:30:14,700 which says, So-and-so is licensed by the city of 671 00:30:14,700 --> 00:30:17,760 whatever to drive this cab. 672 00:30:17,760 --> 00:30:20,300 The government issues a certain amount of these 673 00:30:20,300 --> 00:30:21,390 taxicab medallions. 674 00:30:21,390 --> 00:30:25,570 And almost always issues less than would be demanded in the 675 00:30:25,570 --> 00:30:27,940 free market for taxicabs. 676 00:30:27,940 --> 00:30:30,510 And let's see what effect that has. 677 00:30:30,510 --> 00:30:31,750 So go to 13-6. 678 00:30:31,750 --> 00:30:33,130 This is getting kind of complicated, but this is an 679 00:30:33,130 --> 00:30:36,460 example of the kind of welfare analysis we can do. 680 00:30:36,460 --> 00:30:39,720 Once we understand these concepts. 681 00:30:39,720 --> 00:30:43,440 Let's say we start at point E1. 682 00:30:43,440 --> 00:30:45,670 Big E1 on the right, little E1 on the left. 683 00:30:45,670 --> 00:30:49,880 So on the right-hand side, this is like our other profit 684 00:30:49,880 --> 00:30:52,380 diagrams. The right-hand side is the market. 685 00:30:52,380 --> 00:30:56,890 The left-hand side is an individual cab firm. 686 00:30:56,890 --> 00:31:01,470 Initially, if the government doesn't interfere, you are in 687 00:31:01,470 --> 00:31:05,270 equilibrium at point E sub 1. 688 00:31:05,270 --> 00:31:13,110 Which is, that the price is P1, and the individual cab 689 00:31:13,110 --> 00:31:15,740 firm delivers q sub 1 rides. 690 00:31:15,740 --> 00:31:18,090 And let's assume cab firms are identical, 691 00:31:18,090 --> 00:31:18,790 just to make it easy. 692 00:31:18,790 --> 00:31:20,280 And that there are n of them. 693 00:31:20,280 --> 00:31:24,230 Well in that case, the total amount delivered is N1 Q1. 694 00:31:24,230 --> 00:31:29,610 So Q sub 1 is q sub 1, which is the amount delivered by a 695 00:31:29,610 --> 00:31:32,860 given cab firm at that price, times the n cab 696 00:31:32,860 --> 00:31:34,190 firms in the market. 697 00:31:34,190 --> 00:31:36,990 N1 cab firms in the market. 698 00:31:36,990 --> 00:31:38,630 So there's N1 firms. Each delivers 699 00:31:38,630 --> 00:31:40,580 little q sub 1 of rides. 700 00:31:40,580 --> 00:31:44,820 And you can see at that point, they each make some profit. 701 00:31:44,820 --> 00:31:48,030 So what you can see at that point is that at E1, at a 702 00:31:48,030 --> 00:31:54,910 price of P1, they're making some profit. 703 00:31:54,910 --> 00:31:57,850 The price is set equal to their marginal cost. 704 00:31:57,850 --> 00:31:58,610 I'm sorry, they're not making a profit. 705 00:31:58,610 --> 00:31:59,150 My bad. 706 00:31:59,150 --> 00:32:01,690 You see at that point they're not making profit. 707 00:32:01,690 --> 00:32:03,545 Because what you can see is price is equal to the minimum 708 00:32:03,545 --> 00:32:06,550 of average cost. Remember, the no-profit condition is where 709 00:32:06,550 --> 00:32:09,980 marginal cost equals average cost. You can see at that 710 00:32:09,980 --> 00:32:11,630 point, little e1 in the diagram at the 711 00:32:11,630 --> 00:32:14,960 left, there is no profit. 712 00:32:14,960 --> 00:32:18,440 Because price equals marginal cost, equals the average cost. 713 00:32:18,440 --> 00:32:20,590 So we're making no profit, and that's a perfectly competitive 714 00:32:20,590 --> 00:32:21,020 equilibrium. 715 00:32:21,020 --> 00:32:23,510 That's what we derived last time. 716 00:32:23,510 --> 00:32:24,910 Now, let's say the government comes in and 717 00:32:24,910 --> 00:32:26,160 says, you know what? 718 00:32:28,840 --> 00:32:29,750 And the welfare here. 719 00:32:29,750 --> 00:32:31,040 Just to do the welfare here. 720 00:32:31,040 --> 00:32:33,550 You see that the welfare of society is, 721 00:32:33,550 --> 00:32:35,920 producers make no surplus. 722 00:32:35,920 --> 00:32:38,140 There's no producer surplus, there's no profits. 723 00:32:38,140 --> 00:32:42,720 Consumers have surplus of A plus B plus C. So consumer 724 00:32:42,720 --> 00:32:45,730 surplus is the area on the demand curve above the price. 725 00:32:45,730 --> 00:32:48,470 That's A plus B plus C. Producer surplus is profits, 726 00:32:48,470 --> 00:32:49,660 which are zero. 727 00:32:49,660 --> 00:32:51,440 Because it's perfectly competitive. 728 00:32:51,440 --> 00:32:55,370 So you end up with a total social surplus of A plus B 729 00:32:55,370 --> 00:32:59,850 plus C. And it all goes to consumers. 730 00:32:59,850 --> 00:33:03,360 Now let's say, the taxicab owners aren't 731 00:33:03,360 --> 00:33:05,210 so happy about this. 732 00:33:05,210 --> 00:33:07,120 They don't like making zero surplus. 733 00:33:07,120 --> 00:33:10,400 And they manage to get a restriction. 734 00:33:10,400 --> 00:33:12,480 Such that the government says, there's only a certain number 735 00:33:12,480 --> 00:33:13,950 of medallions. 736 00:33:13,950 --> 00:33:17,630 And we're only going to let people drive the cabs if they 737 00:33:17,630 --> 00:33:18,880 have a medallion. 738 00:33:22,110 --> 00:33:25,900 Now, let's say that the taxicab owners say, we're only 739 00:33:25,900 --> 00:33:29,000 going to limit the number of medallions to N sub 2. 740 00:33:29,000 --> 00:33:31,530 Instead of there being n sub 1 cab firms-- let's say 741 00:33:31,530 --> 00:33:33,730 medallions aren't for cabs, they're for cab companies. 742 00:33:33,730 --> 00:33:37,040 Instead of being n sub 1 cab companies, we're going to 743 00:33:37,040 --> 00:33:40,960 limit medallions so there can only be n sub 2 cab companies. 744 00:33:40,960 --> 00:33:42,120 So what happens? 745 00:33:42,120 --> 00:33:43,210 Well, it's a little complicated so 746 00:33:43,210 --> 00:33:44,530 let's follow along. 747 00:33:44,530 --> 00:33:49,250 If there's only n sub 2 cab companies, then what that 748 00:33:49,250 --> 00:33:55,480 means is that given the same market demand, that means 749 00:33:55,480 --> 00:33:59,530 firms are now going to be able to make some profit. 750 00:33:59,530 --> 00:34:05,140 So up to, if you look at the right-hand side diagram up to 751 00:34:05,140 --> 00:34:09,600 N2 Q1, the supply curve is the same. 752 00:34:09,600 --> 00:34:15,670 But at that point, once you pass N2 Q1, then you have a 753 00:34:15,670 --> 00:34:19,320 point where that's-- 754 00:34:19,320 --> 00:34:22,834 at the old, efficient level of cab rides, the efficient level 755 00:34:22,834 --> 00:34:25,860 is, each cab company provides Q sub 1 rides. 756 00:34:25,860 --> 00:34:27,080 Well, you then run out of rides, but 757 00:34:27,080 --> 00:34:28,469 people still want more. 758 00:34:28,469 --> 00:34:29,590 So what happens? 759 00:34:29,590 --> 00:34:33,199 Well, cab companies start to be able to charge more. 760 00:34:33,199 --> 00:34:36,150 The supply curve becomes upward sloping. 761 00:34:36,150 --> 00:34:38,540 They start to be able to charge more for their rides. 762 00:34:38,540 --> 00:34:41,730 Because now you don't have extra cab companies entering 763 00:34:41,730 --> 00:34:43,989 and competing those profits away. 764 00:34:43,989 --> 00:34:47,320 They start to be able to charge more for their rides. 765 00:34:47,320 --> 00:34:51,489 And you see that that upward sloping supply curve meets the 766 00:34:51,489 --> 00:34:56,639 demand curve at N2 Q2. 767 00:34:56,639 --> 00:34:59,490 So up to N2 Q1 it's the supply curve which it 768 00:34:59,490 --> 00:35:00,770 was, which is flat. 769 00:35:00,770 --> 00:35:03,000 Once you get beyond that, now firms can 770 00:35:03,000 --> 00:35:04,230 charge a higher price. 771 00:35:04,230 --> 00:35:06,330 Because they don't have to worry about entry. 772 00:35:06,330 --> 00:35:09,390 So you get a new supply curve that's flat until N2 Q1 then 773 00:35:09,390 --> 00:35:10,300 starts to slope up. 774 00:35:10,300 --> 00:35:12,210 That's S super 2. 775 00:35:12,210 --> 00:35:17,960 And S super 2 intersects the demand curve at point E sub 2. 776 00:35:17,960 --> 00:35:20,600 And that is the new equilibrium, with the higher 777 00:35:20,600 --> 00:35:26,880 price of P2 and a lower total quantity of Q2. 778 00:35:26,880 --> 00:35:28,390 Now let's what that does to the firm. 779 00:35:28,390 --> 00:35:33,980 Well, a given firm at a price P2, they now-- 780 00:35:33,980 --> 00:35:35,270 they always set the price equal to marginal 781 00:35:35,270 --> 00:35:36,430 cost. That's the rule. 782 00:35:36,430 --> 00:35:38,810 Every profit maximizing firm does that. 783 00:35:38,810 --> 00:35:43,160 Well, they now are at a point little e sub 2, 784 00:35:43,160 --> 00:35:44,950 making a huge profit. 785 00:35:44,950 --> 00:35:47,860 Because at that point, their marginal cost is well above 786 00:35:47,860 --> 00:35:52,100 their average cost. So at that point, they make the profit of 787 00:35:52,100 --> 00:35:55,750 the shaded area pi in the left-hand side diagram. 788 00:35:55,750 --> 00:35:58,560 They make the profit pi, because once again [INAUDIBLE] 789 00:35:58,560 --> 00:36:00,613 go to the right-hand and then back to the left-hand side. 790 00:36:00,613 --> 00:36:02,940 The right-hand side is, the new supply curve intersects 791 00:36:02,940 --> 00:36:04,330 the demand curve. 792 00:36:04,330 --> 00:36:05,850 At point E2. 793 00:36:05,850 --> 00:36:07,780 That's the price of P2. 794 00:36:07,780 --> 00:36:10,930 Carry that over the left-hand diagram, you see at a price of 795 00:36:10,930 --> 00:36:13,960 P2, they make a profit, the difference between that price 796 00:36:13,960 --> 00:36:18,580 and the average cost curve, which is that shaded pi box. 797 00:36:18,580 --> 00:36:21,010 So firms now make profits. 798 00:36:21,010 --> 00:36:23,030 And they didn't before. 799 00:36:23,030 --> 00:36:26,700 What's happened to welfare in the market? 800 00:36:26,700 --> 00:36:29,980 Well, what's happened is consumer surplus has now 801 00:36:29,980 --> 00:36:35,410 fallen from A plus B to just A. Because the 802 00:36:35,410 --> 00:36:37,280 price is now P2. 803 00:36:37,280 --> 00:36:39,490 The consumer surplus is the area under the demand curve 804 00:36:39,490 --> 00:36:40,450 above the price. 805 00:36:40,450 --> 00:36:45,370 That's just the triangle A. Just the triangle A. At that 806 00:36:45,370 --> 00:36:46,940 new price, that's the consumer surplus. 807 00:36:46,940 --> 00:36:48,880 What's the producer surplus? 808 00:36:48,880 --> 00:36:51,120 Well, now producers are making profits. 809 00:36:51,120 --> 00:36:53,320 And what they're making a surplus is the area below the 810 00:36:53,320 --> 00:36:55,700 price above their supply curve. 811 00:36:55,700 --> 00:36:58,940 The supply curve is this funky kinked thing I just described. 812 00:36:58,940 --> 00:37:02,480 So their new producer surplus is this, I don't know what the 813 00:37:02,480 --> 00:37:04,530 name is for, like a trapezoid with a curved side. 814 00:37:04,530 --> 00:37:06,050 Does that have a name? 815 00:37:06,050 --> 00:37:06,575 It's still a trapezoid? 816 00:37:06,575 --> 00:37:07,770 I don't know. 817 00:37:07,770 --> 00:37:08,700 Anyway. 818 00:37:08,700 --> 00:37:10,890 Curvazoid. 819 00:37:10,890 --> 00:37:16,810 B. Their new surplus is B. So producers now make surplus B. 820 00:37:16,810 --> 00:37:20,230 Consumer surplus is reduced to A. And what's happened to C? 821 00:37:20,230 --> 00:37:21,620 C is gone. 822 00:37:21,620 --> 00:37:23,200 C is dead weight loss. 823 00:37:23,200 --> 00:37:27,080 Consumer surplus is now A. Producer surplus is now B. The 824 00:37:27,080 --> 00:37:30,640 darkly shaded area C is now the dead weight loss. 825 00:37:30,640 --> 00:37:33,150 And that's the dead weight loss, because once again, at 826 00:37:33,150 --> 00:37:35,920 the old marginal cost curve, at the old supply curve, these 827 00:37:35,920 --> 00:37:39,910 are trades which both the producer, which is the taxicab 828 00:37:39,910 --> 00:37:42,690 company, and the consumer, which is a person riding the 829 00:37:42,690 --> 00:37:44,820 taxi, were happy to make. 830 00:37:44,820 --> 00:37:46,460 And they're not being made now. 831 00:37:46,460 --> 00:37:55,880 So we've now lost an amount C, dead weight loss. 832 00:37:55,880 --> 00:37:56,610 Sorry about the confusion. 833 00:37:56,610 --> 00:37:59,730 Questions about that? 834 00:37:59,730 --> 00:38:02,260 Now, here's my question for you. 835 00:38:02,260 --> 00:38:04,170 You can go home and think about that, and hopefully 836 00:38:04,170 --> 00:38:05,450 it'll be clear in the examples on Friday. 837 00:38:05,450 --> 00:38:07,920 But let's ask a slightly deeper question. 838 00:38:07,920 --> 00:38:14,020 Does this mean that if you become a taxi driver today, 839 00:38:14,020 --> 00:38:16,910 you will derive producer surplus of B 840 00:38:16,910 --> 00:38:19,270 from driving a taxi? 841 00:38:19,270 --> 00:38:19,860 Why not? 842 00:38:19,860 --> 00:38:23,030 AUDIENCE: Because you have to pay that lump sum to get-- 843 00:38:23,030 --> 00:38:25,830 PROFESSOR: Because the point is, you have to get into the 844 00:38:25,830 --> 00:38:28,560 market, and to get into the market you need a medallion. 845 00:38:28,560 --> 00:38:30,010 And the guys with the medallions isn't going to hand 846 00:38:30,010 --> 00:38:30,710 them over to you for free. 847 00:38:30,710 --> 00:38:33,780 So let's say this guy's retiring as a cab driver. 848 00:38:33,780 --> 00:38:35,390 He's got his medallion. 849 00:38:35,390 --> 00:38:36,870 You come up him and say, I want to be a cab driver 850 00:38:36,870 --> 00:38:40,320 because I see this big producer surplus area B. 851 00:38:40,320 --> 00:38:41,890 [INAUDIBLE] medallion. 852 00:38:41,890 --> 00:38:43,240 What's this guy going to say? 853 00:38:43,240 --> 00:38:44,590 He's going to say, well, wait a second. 854 00:38:44,590 --> 00:38:46,680 If I give you my medallion, you're going to make that 855 00:38:46,680 --> 00:38:49,130 profits of pi. 856 00:38:49,130 --> 00:38:50,750 That's the profit you make by being a taxi 857 00:38:50,750 --> 00:38:52,970 driver in this market. 858 00:38:52,970 --> 00:38:57,420 So what should he do? 859 00:38:57,420 --> 00:38:58,760 What should he do? 860 00:38:58,760 --> 00:38:59,615 AUDIENCE: Sell it to you. 861 00:38:59,615 --> 00:39:00,830 PROFESSOR: He should sell it to you. 862 00:39:00,830 --> 00:39:03,820 And how much should he sell it to you for? 863 00:39:03,820 --> 00:39:06,360 Pi minus a penny. 864 00:39:06,360 --> 00:39:07,740 And you might say, well, that's ridiculous. 865 00:39:07,740 --> 00:39:08,850 I won't pay pi minus a penny. 866 00:39:08,850 --> 00:39:09,670 Then I'll make nothing. 867 00:39:09,670 --> 00:39:10,910 Well, but he will. 868 00:39:10,910 --> 00:39:12,435 He'll pay minus a penny because at least 869 00:39:12,435 --> 00:39:14,520 he'll make a penny. 870 00:39:14,520 --> 00:39:17,470 Now, you might say a penny, a dollar, $5, $10 whatever. 871 00:39:17,470 --> 00:39:20,870 But the point is that he'll sell it for very close to pi. 872 00:39:20,870 --> 00:39:25,780 Because there's someone out there who's willing to pay 873 00:39:25,780 --> 00:39:27,000 close to pi to get that. 874 00:39:27,000 --> 00:39:28,210 As long as there's a little bit left. 875 00:39:28,210 --> 00:39:31,600 So it's a little bit less than pi. 876 00:39:31,600 --> 00:39:32,540 They'll pay it. 877 00:39:32,540 --> 00:39:34,640 But what that means is having paid it, you 878 00:39:34,640 --> 00:39:36,280 don't make any money. 879 00:39:36,280 --> 00:39:39,970 So let's do the extreme example where he's willing to 880 00:39:39,970 --> 00:39:42,240 sell it for $1 less than pi. 881 00:39:42,240 --> 00:39:44,420 What that means is you having bought it for $1 less than pi, 882 00:39:44,420 --> 00:39:47,350 you don't make any money as a cab driver. 883 00:39:47,350 --> 00:39:47,990 So wait a second. 884 00:39:47,990 --> 00:39:48,690 This is weird. 885 00:39:48,690 --> 00:39:51,200 We've just restricted the market. 886 00:39:51,200 --> 00:39:53,170 We've said there's all this profit to be made. 887 00:39:53,170 --> 00:39:55,730 And yet you're a cab driver and you make no profit. 888 00:39:55,730 --> 00:39:58,050 What happened to the profit? 889 00:39:58,050 --> 00:39:59,194 Who got it? 890 00:39:59,194 --> 00:40:01,010 AUDIENCE: [UNINTELLIGIBLE] 891 00:40:01,010 --> 00:40:03,140 PROFESSOR: The cab drivers who were originally issued the 892 00:40:03,140 --> 00:40:04,260 medallions. 893 00:40:04,260 --> 00:40:06,310 The first generation cab drivers who got the medallions 894 00:40:06,310 --> 00:40:08,580 got all the money. 895 00:40:08,580 --> 00:40:14,560 So in fact, taxicab medallions do nothing [INAUDIBLE] 896 00:40:14,560 --> 00:40:16,800 taxi drivers. 897 00:40:16,800 --> 00:40:19,160 All they do is enrich the set of people who originally 898 00:40:19,160 --> 00:40:22,090 lobbied for them and got them. 899 00:40:22,090 --> 00:40:22,450 OK. 900 00:40:22,450 --> 00:40:22,870 Yeah. 901 00:40:22,870 --> 00:40:25,270 AUDIENCE: But wouldn't he make his money back the same day he 902 00:40:25,270 --> 00:40:31,380 sold it, given that he can get the same price for his-- 903 00:40:31,380 --> 00:40:33,520 PROFESSOR: Wouldn't he-- 904 00:40:33,520 --> 00:40:36,350 No, but the point is that basically, what he's done, or 905 00:40:36,350 --> 00:40:37,830 you're saying that when he goes to sell it. 906 00:40:37,830 --> 00:40:39,900 So, in other words, the taxicab medallion is worth a 907 00:40:39,900 --> 00:40:41,660 certain amount of money. 908 00:40:41,660 --> 00:40:45,470 But that would be embedded in the money he would charge you. 909 00:40:45,470 --> 00:40:46,810 So he's not dumb. 910 00:40:46,810 --> 00:40:48,763 He's straightening out the supply curve, he's a smart 911 00:40:48,763 --> 00:40:49,710 guy, you should have picked someone else 912 00:40:49,710 --> 00:40:51,550 to negotiate with. 913 00:40:51,550 --> 00:40:54,050 He's going to say, look, I'm going to charge you enough so 914 00:40:54,050 --> 00:40:59,316 that you'll only make $10 forever on having this. 915 00:40:59,316 --> 00:41:02,150 I'm going to charge you enough so that basically, you will 916 00:41:02,150 --> 00:41:06,900 not make any money even when you go to get rid of it. 917 00:41:06,900 --> 00:41:08,410 So basically, what you'll do is, you'll have 918 00:41:08,410 --> 00:41:09,310 to pay him so much. 919 00:41:09,310 --> 00:41:12,150 So let's say the way it works. 920 00:41:12,150 --> 00:41:12,990 Let me give you an example. 921 00:41:12,990 --> 00:41:14,970 Let me come back to that one in the context of an example. 922 00:41:14,970 --> 00:41:17,390 So what we know is that basically-- 923 00:41:17,390 --> 00:41:18,500 and this is in Perloff, give you some 924 00:41:18,500 --> 00:41:19,650 interesting facts on this. 925 00:41:19,650 --> 00:41:20,660 We know that taxicab 926 00:41:20,660 --> 00:41:22,410 medallions are really limiting. 927 00:41:22,410 --> 00:41:24,590 For example, we know that Tokyo has five times as many 928 00:41:24,590 --> 00:41:26,840 cabs as New York City, despite the fact that New York City's 929 00:41:26,840 --> 00:41:27,850 bigger than Tokyo. 930 00:41:27,850 --> 00:41:29,670 And Washington DC has ten times as 931 00:41:29,670 --> 00:41:31,170 many cabs as San Francisco. 932 00:41:31,170 --> 00:41:33,180 Despite the fact that Washington DC is smaller than 933 00:41:33,180 --> 00:41:33,830 San Francisco. 934 00:41:33,830 --> 00:41:34,630 I'm not from San Francisco. 935 00:41:34,630 --> 00:41:36,210 You can always get a cab in Washington, I don't know how 936 00:41:36,210 --> 00:41:37,710 hard it is to get in San Francisco. 937 00:41:37,710 --> 00:41:40,140 But there's 10 times as many cabs in Washington. 938 00:41:40,140 --> 00:41:42,120 And this is reflected in the value of a permit. 939 00:41:42,120 --> 00:41:47,660 So in San Francisco, what you do, and this is sort of an 940 00:41:47,660 --> 00:41:49,870 easier way to think about it. 941 00:41:49,870 --> 00:41:51,550 What he does is, he doesn't sell you the permit. 942 00:41:51,550 --> 00:41:52,900 In San Francisco they don't sell it. 943 00:41:52,900 --> 00:41:54,680 He rents it to you. 944 00:41:54,680 --> 00:41:55,930 So you never get to own it. 945 00:41:55,930 --> 00:41:57,360 He rents it to you. 946 00:41:57,360 --> 00:42:02,380 And in San Francisco, the typical permit costs $42,000 a 947 00:42:02,380 --> 00:42:03,650 year to rent. 948 00:42:03,650 --> 00:42:06,310 So if you want to be a cab driver, you've got to pay 949 00:42:06,310 --> 00:42:11,650 $42,000 off the top before you earn a dollar. 950 00:42:11,650 --> 00:42:13,430 And then he rents to you, when you're done, he takes it back. 951 00:42:13,430 --> 00:42:15,690 So in substance the way-- now, if he was selling it, I can 952 00:42:15,690 --> 00:42:16,220 describe it to you. 953 00:42:16,220 --> 00:42:18,550 Involves the fact that he would embed your future asset 954 00:42:18,550 --> 00:42:20,050 in his sale price. 955 00:42:20,050 --> 00:42:22,130 That involves some complicated finance that we'll get to 956 00:42:22,130 --> 00:42:23,370 later in the course. 957 00:42:23,370 --> 00:42:25,310 So think about renting it, that's easier. 958 00:42:25,310 --> 00:42:27,840 He'll rent it to you for the entire surplus 959 00:42:27,840 --> 00:42:30,050 pi, or pi minus $10. 960 00:42:30,050 --> 00:42:33,020 And in San Francisco that amounts to $42,000 a year. 961 00:42:33,020 --> 00:42:36,590 In New York, New York originally had 12,000 permits 962 00:42:36,590 --> 00:42:40,380 they issued in 1937. 963 00:42:40,380 --> 00:42:43,380 They issued 12,000 permits for $10 each. 964 00:42:43,380 --> 00:42:46,740 They have not issued a new one since. 965 00:42:46,740 --> 00:42:49,250 Literally, there are no more cabs allowed in New York City 966 00:42:49,250 --> 00:42:52,740 than there were in 1937. 967 00:42:52,740 --> 00:42:57,960 A typical taxicab medallion, which sold for $10 in 1937, 968 00:42:57,960 --> 00:43:02,570 now sells for $400,000. 969 00:43:02,570 --> 00:43:03,820 Now once again, you typically don't sell. 970 00:43:03,820 --> 00:43:05,090 You typically rent it out. 971 00:43:05,090 --> 00:43:07,610 But the point is, that taxicab medallion, which embeds the 972 00:43:07,610 --> 00:43:09,880 entire future stream of having the right to drive that 973 00:43:09,880 --> 00:43:11,920 taxicab, is worth $400,000. 974 00:43:11,920 --> 00:43:13,870 So what have we done here? 975 00:43:13,870 --> 00:43:17,580 What we've done-- and in Boston, by the way, a taxicab 976 00:43:17,580 --> 00:43:19,100 medallion's worth about $250,000. 977 00:43:19,100 --> 00:43:21,010 Think about that the next time you're standing in the rain 978 00:43:21,010 --> 00:43:23,340 waiting for a cab. 979 00:43:23,340 --> 00:43:25,010 You're standing in the rain waiting for a cab because some 980 00:43:25,010 --> 00:43:28,480 guy in 1930-something got a grant from the government 981 00:43:28,480 --> 00:43:30,230 worth $250,000. 982 00:43:30,230 --> 00:43:33,270 But the current cab drivers don't get crap. 983 00:43:33,270 --> 00:43:36,690 A taxicab driver in your city makes $10-12 an hour. 984 00:43:36,690 --> 00:43:38,920 It's not a very fun job being a taxicab driver in New York 985 00:43:38,920 --> 00:43:41,010 City, unless you like taking your life in your hands every 986 00:43:41,010 --> 00:43:43,950 time you go out on the streets of New York City. 987 00:43:43,950 --> 00:43:46,400 They make $10 to $12 an hour. 988 00:43:46,400 --> 00:43:48,210 After paying the enormous amount they have to pay to 989 00:43:48,210 --> 00:43:50,600 rent their taxicab medallion. 990 00:43:50,600 --> 00:43:53,870 Now, this is not the only example we have in the world 991 00:43:53,870 --> 00:43:56,940 of something we call occupational restrictions. 992 00:43:56,940 --> 00:43:58,690 There's lots of examples. 993 00:43:58,690 --> 00:44:00,580 Probably the most prominent example, that may be relevant 994 00:44:00,580 --> 00:44:00,980 to some of you. 995 00:44:00,980 --> 00:44:03,480 I hope the taxi cab driver won't be relevant to you guys. 996 00:44:03,480 --> 00:44:06,440 But the doctor example might be. 997 00:44:06,440 --> 00:44:09,370 A great occupational restriction is the AMA and the 998 00:44:09,370 --> 00:44:12,060 education, the institute that educates doctors puts a limit 999 00:44:12,060 --> 00:44:15,180 on the number of medical residency slots, that 1000 00:44:15,180 --> 00:44:17,750 determines how many doctors there can be in America. 1001 00:44:17,750 --> 00:44:22,280 As a result, we all pay more to go for our medical care, 1002 00:44:22,280 --> 00:44:25,010 than we would if more doctors were allowed. 1003 00:44:25,010 --> 00:44:26,200 And you might say, that's outrageous. 1004 00:44:26,200 --> 00:44:30,200 But why, obviously, how would the AMA defend this? 1005 00:44:30,200 --> 00:44:34,560 And how would you defend any occupational license? 1006 00:44:34,560 --> 00:44:35,422 Yeah. 1007 00:44:35,422 --> 00:44:38,380 AUDIENCE: The smaller the amount of [UNINTELLIGIBLE]. 1008 00:44:38,380 --> 00:44:38,586 PROFESSOR: Yeah. 1009 00:44:38,586 --> 00:44:40,980 You don't want everybody being Dr. Nick. 1010 00:44:40,980 --> 00:44:41,710 You want-- 1011 00:44:41,710 --> 00:44:44,040 come on, you guys got to get Dr. Nick. 1012 00:44:44,040 --> 00:44:44,938 Raise your hand if you know what I mean 1013 00:44:44,938 --> 00:44:48,090 when I say Dr. Nick. 1014 00:44:48,090 --> 00:44:50,590 Good lord, what is wrong with you people? 1015 00:44:50,590 --> 00:44:54,496 OK, homework for this course, you've got to watch one 1016 00:44:54,496 --> 00:44:55,430 episode of The Simpsons. 1017 00:44:55,430 --> 00:44:56,770 Before the end of the term. 1018 00:44:56,770 --> 00:44:58,440 This is crazy. 1019 00:44:58,440 --> 00:45:00,060 Dr. Nick is the terrible doctor on The Simpsons. 1020 00:45:00,060 --> 00:45:03,680 You don't want this terrible doctor. 1021 00:45:03,680 --> 00:45:05,270 You don't want these terrible doctors operating on people, 1022 00:45:05,270 --> 00:45:08,170 so we have these restrictions to make sure doctors are good. 1023 00:45:08,170 --> 00:45:09,910 And it sounds like a good idea. 1024 00:45:09,910 --> 00:45:11,400 But next time you hear it, remember. 1025 00:45:11,400 --> 00:45:13,540 It's not just making sure there are good doctors. 1026 00:45:13,540 --> 00:45:14,860 There are probably plenty of people who would be good 1027 00:45:14,860 --> 00:45:16,420 enough doctors who aren't let in because there are not 1028 00:45:16,420 --> 00:45:17,190 enough slots. 1029 00:45:17,190 --> 00:45:19,330 It's also a way to make sure doctors earn lots of money. 1030 00:45:19,330 --> 00:45:21,250 And it's not just the government that does this. 1031 00:45:21,250 --> 00:45:22,880 There's no government involvement here. 1032 00:45:22,880 --> 00:45:26,050 These are private associations which license. 1033 00:45:26,050 --> 00:45:31,720 And they restrict, plumbers, and doctors and optometrists, 1034 00:45:31,720 --> 00:45:34,270 and all these other things are limited. 1035 00:45:34,270 --> 00:45:38,630 Ostensibly to keep quality up, but in reality often to make 1036 00:45:38,630 --> 00:45:40,970 sure that there's some surplus being earned by this initial 1037 00:45:40,970 --> 00:45:42,490 generation who puts puts them in place. 1038 00:45:42,490 --> 00:45:43,250 Yeah. 1039 00:45:43,250 --> 00:45:46,696 AUDIENCE: So is the relative effect on the market smaller 1040 00:45:46,696 --> 00:45:48,655 for doctors because they're not 1041 00:45:48,655 --> 00:45:50,950 selling each other permits? 1042 00:45:50,950 --> 00:45:52,210 PROFESSOR: Well, what's different with the doctors is, 1043 00:45:52,210 --> 00:45:55,620 since it's not a permit but an ongoing limit, then every 1044 00:45:55,620 --> 00:45:56,710 doctor makes the pi. 1045 00:45:56,710 --> 00:45:57,920 There's no selling. 1046 00:45:57,920 --> 00:46:00,940 So the effect on the market is no different. 1047 00:46:00,940 --> 00:46:03,500 So imagine here, instead of it being a medallion, there's a 1048 00:46:03,500 --> 00:46:06,030 limit on how many cabs could run. 1049 00:46:06,030 --> 00:46:08,920 And that limit was randomly reallocated. 1050 00:46:08,920 --> 00:46:12,180 Cab ran out, and then new people went in. 1051 00:46:12,180 --> 00:46:14,280 Then each generation would-- then you wouldn't get the 1052 00:46:14,280 --> 00:46:15,340 thing where the first generation wins. 1053 00:46:15,340 --> 00:46:16,070 Each generation should win. 1054 00:46:16,070 --> 00:46:18,420 But you still get the same distortion of the market. 1055 00:46:18,420 --> 00:46:19,400 The same profit being made. 1056 00:46:19,400 --> 00:46:20,850 It's just that instead of the profit all accruing to the 1057 00:46:20,850 --> 00:46:23,260 first generation, there'd be an ongoing approval of that 1058 00:46:23,260 --> 00:46:25,300 profit to each generation of doctors. 1059 00:46:25,300 --> 00:46:25,892 Yeah. 1060 00:46:25,892 --> 00:46:27,614 AUDIENCE: Professors and tenure, is that 1061 00:46:27,614 --> 00:46:28,850 also related to-- 1062 00:46:28,850 --> 00:46:30,340 PROFESSOR: Professors and tenure would be another very 1063 00:46:30,340 --> 00:46:32,030 good example. 1064 00:46:32,030 --> 00:46:34,400 Basically, an occupational restriction. 1065 00:46:34,400 --> 00:46:38,410 The difference is there's no limit to how many tenured 1066 00:46:38,410 --> 00:46:39,740 professors there can be. 1067 00:46:39,740 --> 00:46:42,040 So basically there's no sense in which, if there's more 1068 00:46:42,040 --> 00:46:43,940 demand for education, a new university couldn't start up 1069 00:46:43,940 --> 00:46:45,320 and have tenured professors. 1070 00:46:45,320 --> 00:46:46,750 There's no situation in which a university couldn't just 1071 00:46:46,750 --> 00:46:48,670 say, we're given tenure to any Tom, Dick, and Harry who walks 1072 00:46:48,670 --> 00:46:49,810 in off the street. 1073 00:46:49,810 --> 00:46:51,490 There's no stopping that, because tenure is determined 1074 00:46:51,490 --> 00:46:52,750 by the institution. 1075 00:46:52,750 --> 00:46:54,680 So in that sense it's not an occupational license, because 1076 00:46:54,680 --> 00:46:56,910 there's no board which determines tenure standards. 1077 00:46:56,910 --> 00:46:58,160 Thank goodness. 1078 00:47:00,140 --> 00:47:01,060 So we'll come back. 1079 00:47:01,060 --> 00:47:02,230 So that's what we were talking about welfare. 1080 00:47:02,230 --> 00:47:04,000 You'll review this more in section on Friday. 1081 00:47:04,000 --> 00:47:05,760 On Wednesday we'll come back to talk about monopoly.